Stewart Wood writes:
On Friday, Ed Miliband pledged to introduce
greater competition in our banking market. Last September, he pledged to freeze
energy prices for 20 months while our broken energy market is reset to expand
competition and consumer choice.
Reforming broken markets to increase competition
and address the long-term sources of our cost-of-living crisis might seem an
unusual theme for Labour to champion.
In fact it is an approach that has learnt from a progressive conservative tradition, one that understands the importance of reform to ensure that markets remain open and competitive.
In fact it is an approach that has learnt from a progressive conservative tradition, one that understands the importance of reform to ensure that markets remain open and competitive.
No one understood this idea better than the
American President Theodore Roosevelt – a passionate believer in free
enterprise, and a tenacious advocate of market reform.
Roosevelt became the 26th President of the United
States in 1901, when William McKinley was assassinated just under a year after
taking office for his second term.
It was a period of Republican ascendancy in America: for 24 of the previous 32 years a Republican had occupied the White House.
It was a period of Republican ascendancy in America: for 24 of the previous 32 years a Republican had occupied the White House.
This was the era of rapid economic expansion, when the USA was
undergoing the transition from the agricultural economy ravaged by Civil War of
the 1860s to becoming the world’s industrial powerhouse.
Yet the 1890s had been lean years for many
Americans. The Depression following the stock market crash of 1893 brought
misery to millions. Thousands of businesses shut down, unemployment soared,
wages declined and soup kitchens opened across the country to help the
destitute.
As Doris Kearns Goodwin puts it, ‘an immense gulf had opened between
the rich and poor; daily existence had become more difficult for ordinary
people, and the middle class increasingly felt squeezed.’
The experience of the 1890s convinced Roosevelt
that continued prosperity, and the widespread enjoyment of the fruits of
prosperity, needed a different approach to government than the economically
laissez-faire Republican Party had hitherto advocated.
The good times had
returned for many by 1901, but Roosevelt knew that politics had fallen out of
touch with a changed America, and had to catch up.
Roosevelt understood three central truths about
the economic condition of his country.
First, that the foundation of true prosperity was
not the interests of the privileged few, but the enterprise of ordinary
Americans, ‘the greater number of small men who are decent, industrious and
energetic’.
Second, that economic success brought
concentration of economic power in industry and banking – resulting in large
corporations (or ‘trusts’) whose dominance kept prices high and competition
low.
These were ‘tendencies hurtful to the general welfare’ and produced in Roosevelt the ‘sincere conviction that combination and concentration should be, not prohibited, but supervised and within reasonable limits controlled’.
These were ‘tendencies hurtful to the general welfare’ and produced in Roosevelt the ‘sincere conviction that combination and concentration should be, not prohibited, but supervised and within reasonable limits controlled’.
Third, that protecting the interests of ordinary
Americans – as entrepreneurs, workers and consumers – demanded an active
government that was on their side. ‘No one matter is of such vital moment to
our whole people as the welfare of the wage-workers’, Roosevelt said in 1901.
It was this philosophy that lay behind
Roosevelt’s demand for a ‘Square Deal’ for Americans: checking the market power
of huge corporations in areas such as banking and railways, protecting workers
against oppressive terms of employment, and introducing unprecedented
protection for consumers.
Though a conservative by instinct, Roosevelt knew
that to protect the competition and enterprise on which prosperity depends, a
different kind of approach to government was needed from the Republican
administrations of the past.
He spoke of ‘constructive statesmanship for the
purpose of broadening our markets and securing our business interests on a safe
basis’.
It required reform of markets that weren’t working in the public
interest, practical regulation to prevent excessive concentration of power, and
new bodies to exercise oversight to ensure the rules were observed.
Active
government, in Roosevelt’s view, was not the enemy of a free economy, but was
essential to secure the conditions under which a free economy can both work,
and work in the interests of all.
A century later, and an ocean away, David
Cameron’s Conservative Party seems impervious to the wisdom of Roosevelt’s
progressivism.
In their view, a nation’s prosperity is first and foremost based
on the efforts of those at the very top; while concentration of economic power
holds no threat to the sustainability of the recovery or the cost of living
crisis faced by tens of millions.
George Osborne’s anaemic efforts at reform of
banking, and his characterisation of Labour’s energy reforms as straight out of
Das Kapital, reveal a conviction that the attempt to repair broken markets is
foolish and dangerous.
It is an assumption of an automatic affinity between the
interests of the private sector and the public interest that would have shocked
Teddy Roosevelt, the progressive conservative.
Curious as it may seem, Labour under Ed Miliband
is better placed to understand the enduring wisdom of Roosevelt’s
progressivism.
We have shown that in our banking and utilities, we want open
competition, not broken competition.
We understand that prosperity depends on the energy and enterprise of the many, which is why we reject trickle down economics and prioritising tax-cuts for the most well-off.
We understand that prosperity depends on the energy and enterprise of the many, which is why we reject trickle down economics and prioritising tax-cuts for the most well-off.
We understand that
sensible reform to bring about greater competition – in banking, energy and
elsewhere – is not the enemy of free enterprise and efficiency, but its
precondition.
Where does that leave David Cameron’s Tory Party?
Wedded to an approach that favours wealth over enterprise, the status quo over
reform, and vested interests over the public interest.
And we can do better
than that.
No comments:
Post a Comment