Bryan
Gould writes:
Credit Creation for
Productive Investment
The most important of the measures needed to
build on a base of improved competitiveness is a second major policy initiative
- the provision of sufficient credit for investment purposes. We have grown so
accustomed, after nearly four decades of monetarism, to regarding control of
the money supply as relevant only to the battle against inflation that we have
lost sight of how essential is an accommodating monetary policy if growth is to
be secured.
The monetarist approach takes a narrowly focused,
backward-looking and static view of the economy; it treats monetary policy as
though it were a minefield, and any growth in the money supply as a dangerous
beast that must be kept strictly muzzled and leashed.
The consequence is that monetarism has become a
recipe for slow growth and high unemployment. As soon as there is any sign of
growth, an almost superstitious fear of inflation (which is almost always code
for a potential rise in wage levels) dictates that demand must be choked off
and job growth restrained. Monetarism looks at only one side of the supply and
demand equation; it totally overlooks the potential of a market economy to grow
and the importance of liquidity and the availability of investment capital in
allowing it to do so - even more surprising when one considers that the
proponents of monetarism claim to be the most committed supporters of the
“free” market.
In addition to its intrinsically anti-growth
stance, monetarist policy requires, through its reliance on higher interest
rates as a counter-inflation tool, that the cost of borrowing for investment is
forced up and becomes a further barrier to improved competitiveness. Higher
interest rates, and the consequently high exchange rate, are a poorly focused
and slow-acting counter-inflationary instrument that produces a good deal of collateral
damage while addressing a problem that in recessionary times is hardly the top
priority. The limitations of interest rates as a tool of macro-economic policy
can be clearly seen in the unsuccessful current attempt to use lower interest
rates as a stimulus to an economy mired in recession; without help from other
elements of policy, bringing down interest rates is, as Keynes observed, like
pushing on a piece of string.
But while monetarist theory inhibits us from
realising the possibilities of growth, it does not tell us what is really
happening in respect of inflation and monetary policy. In the real world, there
is virtually no control over the money supply. While the wider economy - and
manufacturing in particular - are continually denied the liquidity and
investment capital they need in the supposed interests of controlling
inflation, there is virtually a private sector free-for-all in terms of credit
creation for non-productive purposes.
In this world, the size of and growth in the
supply of money is almost entirely within the control of the commercial banks,
which are able to create vast volumes of credit at the stroke of a computer
key. The interest of the banks is of course to lend as much as possible, and
they do so, constrained only by their own need for security if irresponsible
lending goes wrong. As a result, bank lending (or, as we should say, bank
credit creation) is mainly devoted to lending secured by property, which means
in most cases, residential properties which are the most reliable and easily
realised form of security.
This is not only damaging in itself, not least in
the stimulus it provides to inflation, but it also diverts investment capital
away from productive purposes.
Monetarism, in other words, operates so as to shackle
the real economy while being scarcely relevant to the real causes of inflation.
This is in marked contrast to the approach taken at other times and in other
countries. We have focused for so long on restraint and protecting the value of
existing assets rather than creating new wealth that we are simply unfamiliar
with the thinking that has enabled other economies to use monetary policy and
credit creation for productive purposes as essential elements in boosting
economic performance.
History provides compelling evidence to support
Keynes’ pre-war contention that “there are no intrinsic reasons for the
scarcity of capital.” Two of the most striking instances of how credit creation
was used, not to inflate the property market for private profit, but to
stimulate rapid industrial growth, were the United States at the outbreak of
the Second World War, when Roosevelt used the two years before Pearl Harbour to
provide virtually unlimited capital to American industry so that the country
could rapidly multiply its military capability, and Japan in the 1960s and
1970s, when Japanese industry was enabled by similar means to grow at a rapid
rate so as to dominate the world market for mass-produced manufactured goods.
Western economists have typically shown no interest in how this was done and
are almost totally ignorant of the work of leading Japanese economists such as
Shimomura and Kurihara.
More recently, China has used similar techniques
to finance the rapid expansion of Chinese manufacturing. The Chinese central
bank, under instructions from the government, makes credit available to Chinese
enterprises that can demonstrate their ability to comply with the government’s
economic priorities in the course of building or buying new capacity. This is
admittedly, in principle at least, easier to bring about in a totalitarian
regime than in the UK, but in practice there is nothing to stop our government
from requiring the central bank, as the Chinese have done, to create cost-free
credit for specific (and productive) purposes.
The Bank of England has of course already
undertaken quantitative easing on a significant scale, and - interestingly -
this has had no discernible influence on inflation. The difference between that
exercise and what is now required is that the quantitative easing so far
undertaken has merely had the effect of shoring up the banks’ balance sheets,
whereas an effective creation of credit for investment purposes would be
applied directly to the strengthening of our productive base.
Significantly, the incoming governor of the Bank
of England, Mark Carney, has already pointed to this aspect of the policy that
enabled Canada (under his watch) to escape most of the adverse consequences of
the global financial crisis. He has also indicated his interest in adopting a
nominal GDP target rather than inflation as the preferred goal of monetary
policy - a suggestion that immediately indicates a non-standard form of
monetary policy.
Thinking of this kind is rapidly gaining ground.
Leading monetary economists like Adair Turner and Michael Woodford are publicly
debating which precise mechanisms of both fiscal and monetary policy would be
most effective in raising the level of economic activity; they recognise that
the quantitative easing practised so far has failed to focus on this most
desirable outcome.
The rationale underpinning such a strategy is a
simple one. Whereas a sudden expansion in the money supply would, according to
monetarist theory, feed directly into increased inflation, that would be true
only when the economy is already fully utilising its productive capacity; as
Keynes argued, credit creation will not be inflationary if it results in
increased output. As we have seen, orthodox monetarism makes it is all too easy
to assume that there are strict limits to that capacity - unfortunately all too
true of an economy that is fundamentally uncompetitive.
Where an economy is manifestly operating at less
than full capacity, there is no point in restricting the money supply -
especially in the matter of capital for investment. What is needed in a
recession is a lift in demand so that markets at home expand, coupled with an
improvement in competitiveness so that exports are encouraged. In these
circumstances, a deliberate policy of investment credit creation would bring a
double benefit. It would provide readily available finance to support
productive investment and to rebuild a sadly weakened manufacturing base, and
at the same time it would encourage a welcome fall in the value of Sterling as
the foreign exchange markets recognised that this was a deliberate and
long-term goal of policy.
These are both key features of the strategy now
being pursued by Shinzo Abe’s government in Japan - a welcome return to the
policies that served Japan so well in earlier decades and that are justified -
and largely accepted by Japan’s trading partners - on the basis that everyone
will benefit from a more buoyant Japanese economy.
More Helpful Banking
Policies of this kind would be equally welcome
and effective in Western countries if we are to escape from what Paul Krugman
calls the “liquidity trap”, but it is important to understand that enlarging
the monetary base by itself will do little. What matters is what is done with
it. If it simply goes into the banks’ reserves, or is made available so as to
boost demand and consumption in an undirected way, it will miss the point. The
successful example of other countries is that - to be effective in building a
stronger productive base - it must be directed into productive investment.
Sadly, the £16.5 billion of quantitative easing
made available by the Bank of England to the commercial banks through the
funding for lending scheme has failed to show up in increased lending to the
small and medium-sized businesses which desperately need a boost to their
available funding. The excuses trotted out for this failure include the age-old
claim by British banks that the comparatively low level of their lending to
business does not evidence any reluctance to do so, but merely a shortage of
demand - or, to put it another way, a shortage of suitable projects on which to
lend. But no sense of this can be made unless we know not only how much is
available to lend but also - and more importantly - the terms on which the
banks are offering to lend.
And that is precisely, of course, what we are not
allowed to know. The banks are always very coy about the terms they offer. But,
in the absence of information made available by the banks, we are entitled to
make some assumptions on the basis of what is known of the long-term attitude
of the British banking system to lending to industry.
The information that is available shows that, by
comparison with other and more successful economies, our banks lend over a
shorter term - repayment, in other words, has to be made faster. This means
that the annual repayment costs of bank loans for British firms over the life
of the loan are much higher, the adverse impact on cash-flow is therefore more
severe, and the need to make an immediate return on investment (and a quick
boost to profitability) is much greater.
Annual repayment costs that are several multiples
lower than British equivalents are a large part of the reason for the greater
amount and ease of bank borrowing enjoyed by businesses in, for example,
Germany and Japan, and in the new powerhouses of China, Korea and Taiwan - and
that is, of course, why they are able to buy up and make a profit from our
failing assets.
This is the fons et origo of the
much-lamented British disease of short-termism. Short-term cash-flow or
liquidity is at least as important to British firms as longer-term
profitability; indeed, it is literally a matter of life and death. It is a
factor that both inhibits the willingness to borrow (and therefore the access
to essential investment capital) in the first place, and - if the loan is made
- greatly increases the chances that it cannot be repaid in accordance with the
loan period and terms insisted upon by the banks.
If, as is all too likely, a business borrowing on
these terms runs into difficulties before the return on the investment funded
by the borrowing becomes available, the news gets worse. British banks, unlike
their overseas counterparts, show little interest in the survival of their
customers. Their sole concern is to recover the loan and interest payments due
to them over the short period specified in the loan arrangement. If that means
receivership or liquidation - even if the business had a good chance of survival
were the investment plans funded by the loan allowed to proceed - so be it. The
banks can congratulate themselves not only on the return of the loan and other
payments due to them sooner than if the business had been allowed to survive
but also on the money to be made from the disposal of the assets (sometimes to
foreign buyers) and the receivership process.
Many people are vaguely aware of these factors
but our lack of interest in what makes competitor economies more successful
than ours - indeed, our conviction that we have nothing to learn from them -
blinds us to these truths.
It is time we opened our minds and demanded
better from our banking system. And shouldn’t these decisions in any case be
taken in the public interest and not those of self-interested bankers?
No comments:
Post a Comment