Saturday, 25 May 2013

Germany Calling


The poet, playwright, novelist, philosopher and amateur morphologist Johann Wolfgang von Goethe didn’t have many moments of self-doubt, but he was easily impressed by the English.

“As young and 17-year-old as they may be when they turn up here,” he wrote to his friend Johann Eckermann in 1828, “they still never seem foreign or bashful in these German lands; on the contrary, their conduct and demeanour in our society is so full of confidence . . . it is as if they were in charge everywhere and owned every corner of the globe.”

Germany has always been more anglophile than the British dare to imagine, mainly because the British Isles have played an important role in every single one of Germany’s foundation myths. Goethe and Schiller’s “Germany of the mind”, the nation of thinkers and poets? Every child knows that without Shakespeare, it wouldn’t have happened (“Schakespär”, wrote Herder, was destined to “create us Germans”).

Germany the football nation? Hard to imagine without the Fußball-Mutterland. Germany the industrial engine room of Europe? If you look closely enough, you’ll find that each of Germany’s three “economic miracles” carries a discreet British trademark.

In the 19th century, Carl Wilhelm Siemens and Alfried Krupp were eager students of Manchester-Kapitalismus before they became industrial pioneers (both men enthusiastically anglicised their names, to Charles William and Alfred). In the 1940s it was the British occupying forces who repaired the machines at Wolfsburg and opened the way for the rise of Volkswagen.

Even if you believe those, like Angela Merkel, who argue that the country’s current success is mainly down to the supplyside reforms of Gerhard Schröder’s Agenda 2010 reforms, it is hard to ignore how many German politicians who now rail against the excess of “Anglo-Saxon banking” were ten years earlier calling for the need to emulate Britain’s liberal economy.

One curious feature of Anglo-German relations is how seldom that same attitude is mirrored in Britain. Usually every 20 years or so, there is a phase when British politicians and businessmen start whispering conspiratorially about “the German model” – but they tend to be just that: phases.

Margaret Thatcher’s Centre for Policy Studies was founded in 1974 with the stated aim of looking at lessons that could be drawn from the success of the German economy, but ended up somewhere more Austrian. And at the TUC conference in September 1978 a motion was put forward to “adopt the German approach to industrial relations”; the defeat was so resounding that no one even bothered to count the votes.

Today, with British enthusiasm for the German social market model growing on the left, it’s relatively easy to eulogise the Mittelstand, rave about cheap renting in Berlin or rail against German austerity-mania. However, few have the patience to get their head around Germany’s complicated network of craft-based guilds, federal transfers and regional banks.

Yet many of the features that make Germany so successful were, in effect, installed by the British after the Second World War – be they the mandatory representation of workers on management panels, which has helped the country hold on to its industry during labour-market reforms, or the ponderous federal structure of government, which encourages long-term policy strategies over short-term fixes and has arguably made the country a more egalitarian (and happier) place than London-centric Britain. The sociologist Wolfgang Streeck calls these “constructive restraints”: paradoxically, they make Germany more dynamic by making it less flexible.

So the irony may be that the British managed to build a much better political economy from scratch abroad than they were able to grow over centuries in their own backyard – but then turned their back on the country and forgot all about it.

Interestingly, when it comes to the arts, Britain has found much easier to sustain an interest in the value of a mutual flow of influences. English Romanticism is an unashamedly cross-cultural collaboration, born out of Wordsworth’s, Coleridge’s and the Shelleys’ travels through German forests. D H Lawrence ran off with a German wife whose “religious attitude to matters of the body” inspired Lady Chatterley’s Lover.

As for musical innovation, Germany came up with Kraftwerk and Can. In the early days of Joy Division the band’s frontman, Ian Curtis, made a ritual of playing Kraftwerk’s “Trans-Europe Express” over the PA before taking to the stage. It hints at just the right mix of cosmopolitan curiosity and barefaced jingoism: “That’s interesting. Let’s copy it and make it better.” British politicians may want to take note.

And Maurice Glasman writes:

“The lives of the dead hang like a nightmare on the minds of the living,” wrote Marx. His words apply to the relationship between Margaret Thatcher and the Labour Party. She defeated us in life and her ghost was not laid at her funeral. Thatcher’s inheritance still sets the parameters of political rationality and government policy today.

She argued that Labour spent too much, taxed too much and borrowed too much. In terms of what used to be called “ideology”, she fused a theory of human nature (self-interested, patriotic) and history (an adventurous island people weighed down by taxes and regulation) with a theory of reason (markets distribute goods more efficiently than states).

These added up to a political position that could both explain the causes of decline and give a clear orientation for action in the present. Thatcher had a narrative and a strategy, and she generated energy.

The trajectory of the Labour Party over the past 35 years has been defined by the challenge Thatcher posed. What is the alternative to the market as the exclusive generator of innovation? What is the alternative to managerial prerogative in the pursuit of efficiency?

Part of Labour’s challenge is historical: to show that the durability and comparative strength of Europe’s most successful economy – Germany’s, which has come to be understood exclusively as a function of its monetary discipline –was in fact rooted in a series distinctive, decentralised institutions. The “equalisation of burdens” act of 1952 stipulated that there had to be negotiation between capital and labour both inside firms and in society as a whole.

The coming together of Social and Christian Democracy, the latter characterised by a strong commitment to the dignity of labour espoused in Catholic social thought, led to a system of “co-determination”, rather than nationalisation, in which the workforce had significant representation on management boards; and to a vocational system of labour market entry which was organised by democratically elected institutions and by regional banks not permitted to lend outside their area. Sectoral pension funds were run with an equal representation of capital and labour and were based on current rates of earnings. The irony is that these institutions were built after the war in the British zone of occupation, and were signed off by the then foreign secretary, Ernest Bevin.

Incentives to virtue were built into the German system through institutions that renewed knowledge, good practice and intergenerational solidarity. Neither neo-classical nor Keynesian economic theories can conceive of value being generated by anything other than the individual or the state. Neither has a theory of the firm, or of those mediating institutions that preserve and generate value within the economy. Nor is there a vision of Europe that involves the strengthening of decentralised institutions, cities, universities, vocational colleges, regional banks and community-owned football clubs.

The current economic debate is suspended between austerity, on the one hand, and stimulus, on the other. Neither perspective recognises the centrality of conflict and cooperation between classes or institutions, nor do they seek to strengthen the internal practices of good institutions as a necessary condition for flourishing states and markets. Neither offers incentives to virtue nor establishes a common good between previously estranged interests, as happens in the German model.

What Labour should take from the Germans is a governing ideology that understands human nature as based on self-interest broadly conceived, an ideology in which the well-being of others is a condition of our own flourishing, and in which the preservation of quality through the practices of democratically organised, non-pecuniary institutions is as necessary as fiscal discipline and the upholding of individual rights.

The prevailing paradigms cannot explain why the economy with the highest level of workforce participation in its governance, the greatest degree of regulation of labour market entry through vocational enforcement and the most severe constraints on capital in its banking system should be the most competitive in Europe, as well as its most efficient. However, an explanation of the comparative superiority of the German economy should be central to Labour’s new economic offer. We are all in this together in ways that George Osborne cannot begin to understand.

Such a political position requires the following: a reassertion of the value of labour and the representation of the workforce in corporate governance; a renewed role for vocational institutions in reproducing skill; self-organised universities run by academics on the basis of the internal goods of knowledge rather than the external goods of money or policy objectives; self-governing cities with the power to shape the destiny of their citizens; and the endowment of regional banks that can resist the domination of the “Big Six” in internal investment and enable access to capital in regions where there is no nourishment to be found.

A renewal of solidarity in social security and welfare is also required, one that establishes solidarity, subsidiarity and status as guiding principles. A politics of mutual sacrifice is the necessary complement to that of mutual benefit. That is the meaning of reciprocity.

The domination of internal investment by the banks that had to be bailed out following the crash of autumn 2008 must be challenged by the creation of new financial institutions and the renewal of old ones. These should be funded by using 5 per cent of the bailout money to endow new Banks of England.

This would challenge the centralisation of capital, offer an alternative to payday lenders and offer tangible investment to local businesses. Jon Cruddas, in his “earning and belonging” speech in February this year, told the story of how the Northern Counties Permanent Building Society, which was rooted in the north-east of England, survived four depressions, growing through each, but could not survive its demutualisation as Northern Rock in 1997. In maximising returns, the asset was lost and a trusted local institution was destroyed.

The overwhelming lesson of the German economy is that a balance of interests in corporate governance between capital and labour is as necessary as a more relational and localised banking system. Accountability is too important to be left to accountants. The only group with the expertise and an interest that could hold elites accountable and have an interest in the flourishing of the business is the workforce.

This is double-edged: on the one hand, capital must negotiate with labour and share information about firms and their environments. On the other hand, the workforce must commit itself to good standards of work and to the well-being of funders and consumers. The common good is a demanding category.

This offers a constructive alternative to the current government, which is still working with the same failed banking institutions, refuses to make a connection between apprenticeships and labour-market entry, and cannot conceive of a different form of corporate governance.

A state investment bank combined with a continued reliance on migration for skills, without regional investment institutions and vocational colleges that are aware of local realities, could stimulate short-term excitement but would not offer the framework for long-term relationships that are the basis for innovation and growth.

“One-nation” economics is pro-business and pro-worker, and seeks a balance of power in fostering innovation. A more competitive economy requires shared institutions that generate quality and value. Quality and equality are mutually supportive concepts.

That is what is at stake with “one-nation Labour”: the possibility of a life together that is different and better, of a politics of the common good that is equal to the challenges we face and offers partnership to people. Relationships precede action. We need to rediscover the need for each other.

The founder of German social democracy Eduard Bernstein was right: the movement is everything.

1 comment:

  1. The post WWII occupation of Germany really could, and should, be more integrated into histories of Britain and the Empire/Commonwealth.

    ReplyDelete